Looking Forward. By Michael Albert and Robin Hahnel

 Go to Table of Contents

 

  6. Participatory Allocation

 

 

 "Suppose you also have a computer 'credit card' that has all this information stored in its portable memory and which records your consumptions, subtracting them from your year's allotment as you go. "

 

 

 

 

 



 

 

 

 

 Is a participatory planning apparatus too large to implement? In 1987 just over 3 million individuals were employed by the federal government of the United States in nonmilitary posts. (Just under 100 million was the total nonmilitary employment for the country as a whole.) The government positions include 44,000 computer specialists, 60,000 clerk typists, 18,000 lawyers, 23,000 air traffic controllers, 27,000 criminal investigators, 38,000 nurses, and so on. The executive department of the executive branch alone had over I million civilian employees including roughly 116,000 in agriculture, 3 1,000 in defense, 122,000 in health and human services, 4,500 in education, 245,000 in veterans affairs, etc. The federal court system had about 21,000 employees. Would it require more than this to maintain the planning apparatus of a participatory economy?

 

 

 

Updating a Settled Plan

 

Converging and updating are related because each benefits from "tricks" that take advantage of the large scale of planning. Let's assume we have settled on a plan for the year. Why might we need to update the initially agreed on plan as the year evolves, and how might we do so?

 

As a consumer you begin your year with approved requests for different kinds of food, clothing, meals at restaurants, trips, gas, books, records, and tickets to performances you will consume over the year. Suppose you also have a computer "credit card" that has all this information stored in its portable memory and which records your consumptions, subtracting them from your year's allotment as you go. What if you want to change what you consume from what you planned?

 

You belong to a neighborhood council, which in turn belongs to a network of consumer federations. Many changes you propose may be counterbalanced by changes others propose in your neighborhood, ward, county, etc. Obviously consumption changes that cancel one another would not affect production and could be easily accommodated by consumer councils and federations.

 

If I want more of this and less of that, and my neighbor wants the reverse-or, more likely, if the ups and downs of three thousand of us all requesting modest changes in this, that, and the other largely cancel out-then production needn't change significantly. Even if the sum of all changes in proposed consumption of milk by all members of your neighborhood council sum to a significant increase in demand, that total may be balanced by opposite changes in other neighborhood councils so that only distribution is affected.

 

Sometimes, however, changes will not balance so that the net increase, say, in milk demand must be communicated to milk producers, who then either produce more-by increasing work intensity, hours worked by each employee, or adding personnel--or refuse to increase production.

 

Since any increase in milk production will more than likely require more inputs, there would be secondary effects whose impact may cancel out with secondary effects of adjustments in other industries, or may not. If people's consumption is recorded automatically on their "credit card" computers and deducted from their annual allocation, periodic updates could be easily communicated to relevant updating facilitation boards (UFBs) which could in turn communicate projected changes in consumer demand, first to relevant consumer federations, and then, if necessary, to relevant industry federations. In response, workers propose accommodating changes they are willing to undertake and consumers are told the relevant changes they can incorporate into their expectations. Such dialogues can certainly lead to work diminishing in some industries and increasing in others, with transfers of employees as necessary, but there would be no more moving about than in other kinds of economies and probably quite a bit less since the cost of workers having to change jobs would be a factor in the collective determination of whether to meet changed demands.

 

In light of the above we can see that since each council's activities have implications for others, if the matches between supply and demand are calculated too closely in the original plan, changes during the year would more likely disrupt the whole economy. There would be too much moving and debating in a network that was planned too tightly. So to simplify updating, participatory planning incorporates "slack." All industries produce more than planned demand in the first place and also plan excess capacity so they can expand output even further should the occasion arise. Likewise, the plan leaves some extra resource availability. At the same time, individuals would not be allowed to dramatically change their requests without receiving an OK from their consumption council, nor could workers in a company unduly lower output without an OK from their industry council. With these provisos, it ought to be clear that flexibly accommodating changing tastes and possibilities is not beyond the capacity of a participatory economy with appropriate "slack" built in. And before the cynical reader cries "waste," he or she should note that depending on how one measures the contemporary U.S. economy runs with between 15 percent and 25 percent unutilized capacity, and that this is easily two to three times more than what would be needed in a participatory economy.

 

Finally, the law of averages regarding the likelihood of proposed changes offsetting one another and a general social knowledge of those industries most likely to be affected by nonaveraging changes would allow informed "slack planning." During the iterative process, that is, the lFBs would propose relevant slack for various products in tune with past histories and with other variables we will discuss later. These would enter the final plan as some proportion of each unit's output and potential output that would not necessarily be produced.