Looking Forward. By Michael Albert and Robin Hahnel

 Go to Table of Contents

 

  6. Participatory Allocation

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

"Workers desiring goods to enact improvements request them. Workers at plants producing the goods requested decide whether they wish to provide them. The dynamic is like any other consumer/producer interaction."

 

 

 



 

 

 

 

"Differences in consumers' desires and the desires and capabilities of different workers' councils are accounted for, as well as variations in the timing of people’s contributions and receipt of benefits. The pressure brought to bear on participants promotes efficiency and equity, not uniformity."

 

 



 

Going from One Proposal to Another

 

First proposals are in. We have all answered how much and in what form we think we want to work and consume under an optimistic assessment of possibilities. Are we ready to call the resulting aggregate a plan, or must we have another round?

 

To decide we sum all consumption requests and all production proposals and compare demand with supply for every class of good. In the first iteration or round, when consumers are supposed to propose ambitious consumption bundles and workers are supposed to propose desirable work plans, for most goods demand exceeds supply which means everyone's initial proposals cannot be simultaneously implemented. In planning terminology, the initial proposals do not yield a feasible plan and the status of most goods is in excess demand by some percentage.

 

Next, every council receives new data regarding the degree to which goods it offered or requested were in excess supply or excess demand and how its requests compared with those of other units. Did my workplace council offer to produce less than other similar production units; did my consumers' council request a bundle larger than others' consumption requests?

 

lFBs translate excess demands and any excess supplies into appropriate changes in the "indicative" prices for those goods by raising the prices of goods in excess demand and lowering the prices of goods in excess supply, with greater changes the higher the percent of excess demand or supply. The changed indicative prices in turn provide councils new estimates of the social costs and benefits of different items they request or offer to produce.

 

Next since councils must eventually win the approval of other councils for their proposals, consumers' councils are under "peer" pressure to bring their overall consumption requests into line with average per capita consumption, and workers' councils are under "peer'' pressure to bring the ratio of the social benefits of their outputs to the social costs of their inputs up to the national average. But this does not mean that every consumer council must consume the average amount of every item, or that every workplace in an industry must use inputs in the same proportions to make their output. By multiplying the amount of each good requested by its "indicative" price and summing on its computer terminals, each consumers' council can compare the average per member value of its requests to the average per member value of other councils' requests and to the national average. Of course, in the participatory economy "overall value" of a consumption request is just another way of saying the "overall burden on scarce resources and laboring capacities" that a consumption request places on the rest of the economy. Likewise, by multiplying outputs by their indicative prices and summing to attain the total value of products (social benefit), and multiplying inputs by their indicative prices and summing to attain the total value of inputs used (social cost), each workers' council can calculate its own social benefit to social cost ratio for comparison to the ratios of other workplaces and industry and economy-wide averages.

 

With each new round of planning, goods previously in excess demand will have a higher price when councils next decide how much they want and that goods previously in excess supply will have a lower price. These changed prices will create a new context for decision making. Councils will usually revise proposals first by substituting inputs whose indicative prices have fallen for inputs whose indicative prices have risen, and for workplaces, substituting outputs whose indicative prices have risen for outputs whose prices have fallen. These shifting adjustments will promote economic efficiency and alleviate the extent to which individual councils must engage in the other kind of proposal revision, reducing adjustments. But if after making shifting adjustments, the value of a consumption request remains higher than the national average, and if work effort proposals and borrowing/saving plans do not justify the excess, and if no special circumstances are deemed to warrant the excess, and if there is no expectation in the consumers' council that circumstances in coming iterations will change in favor of the council, then the council will feel pressure to reduce its overall request to bring

 

 "The changed indicative prices in turn provide councils new estimates of the social costs and benefits of different items they request or offer to produce."

 

 "With each new iteration, the fact that goods previously in excess demand will have a higher price when councils next decide how much they want and that goods previously in excess supply will have a lower price, will create a new context for decision making."

 


its per-member value into line with the national average. And, likewise, if after shifting adjustments a workers' council still cannot generate an acceptable excess of social benefits over social costs, and if it has no viable excuse (such a greater need) and no sensible expectation that conditions will change in its favor in the following iteration, it will feel pressure to increase its work effort. Moreover, as the rounds of planning proceed, price indicators will begin to approach their final resting places and consumers and workers will have less justification for "holding out" in overly expensive consumption requests or insufficient production offerings expecting new prices to ratify their stance. Ultimately a workplace unable to sufficiently improve its ratio of social benefits to social costs might even be asked to disperse, since it is not in society's interest to permit resources that could be used more productively elsewhere to be used unproductively in such a unit.

 

In the above summary, the essential logic of proposal revision is straightforward: peer review backed by the necessity of getting one's proposal accepted pressures actors to bring their consumption and work proposals "into line," so that people contribute efforts commensurate to the efforts they implicitly demand from others. Ever more accurate estimates of social costs and benefits of goods induce workers and consumers to shift from goods in greater excess demand to goods in greater excess supply thereby promoting the social interest via an efficient allocation of scarce productive resources. Simultaneously, reductions of unacceptably expensive consumption requests or lazy production proposals are promoted. In a context where socially responsible behavior is induced, individual actors receive the information they need to reconcile their individual pursuit of well being with others' equally deserving attempts to do likewise. Differences in consumers' desires and the desires and capabilities of different workers' councils are accounted for, as well as variations in the timing of people's contributions and receipt of benefits. The pressure brought to bear on participants promotes efficiency and equity, not uniformity.

 

Each new round of planning yields a new set of proposed activities for all consumers and producers as well as new estimates of indicative prices, average consumption, and average work productivity. But what propels the process toward a conclusion that everyone will accept? How do we know the final allocation will be superior to what a central planner or market system would have arrived at? Moreover, how do we update when conditions change during the year? We'll address the last concern first, since it helps clarify how the other concerns are addressed.